Trade deals need
careful planning
By Eric Chiouªô«³§»
Do free trade and liberalization benefit everybody and boost a nation¡¦s economy?
Recent controversies over the cross-strait service trade agreement have put this
oft-asked question back in the spotlight. Economists are divided and provide no
definite answers. They are similarly noncommittal on the proliferation of
regional trade agreements around the world. Most people simply assume that,
because of the trade liberalization they bring, trade agreements definitely do
more good than harm to a nation¡¦s economy.
This assumption not only ignores the negative consequences of such an agreement
on an economy, but also wrongly perceives free trade as a panacea to a nation¡¦s
international competitiveness.
The nation seems to be misguided in this manner; it is bewitched by the promise
of trade liberalization and craves attention from its potential partners ¡X
jumping at every trade opportunity, such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)
and the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP).
The economy relies heavily on external trade, but its free-trade agreements
cover only a low ratio of all export goods, so it is understandable that Taiwan
is eager to increase its number of trade partners to improve this ratio and
accelerate its pace of liberalization.
Although the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) government¡¦s earnestness to
increase trade deals is understandable, it may be dangerous if policymakers only
consider the benefits of joining regional trade blocs, but neglect the downside.
They must learn strategic thinking: how to manage risks and use any strengths as
leverage.
Despite numerous studies highlighting favorable results for the economies
involved in trade agreements, it is regrettable that most research fails to
specify potential risks to different industrial sectors. Leaders should not be
so naive to assume that an agreement signifies the arrival of an economic
paradise in which all the people in each member nation have their lives
measurably improved. It is wishful thinking to believe that every industrial
sector will see the same benefits.
There is no substantiation for such thinking, neither theoretically nor
empirically. The theories of international trade say that deeper economic
integration among free trade members is likely to generate better economic
welfare and lead to more reasonable and efficient distribution of resources.
However, these theories do not claim that each industrial sector within the
partner states will benefit equally from the arrangement; neither do these
theories promise that individual sectors will not suffer.
Despite likely increases in overall economic welfare for the members of a trade
region, there is no guarantee of positive effects for every sector. Existing
literature has not explored which industrial sectors in member nations are
likely to receive most gains, let alone describe which sectors will lose out.
Because trade agreements inevitably create winners and losers, policymakers
should be considering the consequences more, rather than painting a rosy picture
of future trade formations. For instance, is it reasonable and right to chase an
agreement after considering the interests of domestic industries? Which sectors
are likely to be winners and which are likely to be more vulnerable? What if the
study of an arrangement shows more harm than good will come to a state¡¦s
prioritized sectors, even though the overall economic projection is good?
For example, the auto industries of several nations are perceived as a prime
industry sector and even a symbol of the national economy. Not only industrial
nations, like the US and Japan, but developing countries, such as China and
India, actively nurture and promote their automobile manufacturers. If the
projections of a trade agreement study showed that it would harm this prize
industry, it is unlikely that any nation would sign it.
My study, presented at the APEC Study Center Consortium Conference in Jakarta,
Indonesia, late last month, said that different trade initiatives toward the
goal of a free-trade area in the Asia-Pacific are likely to create various
winners and losers in each economy and in each of their industrial sectors. The
study investigated the results from three trade formations: the 12 TPP
economies, the 16 RCEP economies and the 21 APEC economies. It also examined the
possible repercussions of these three scenarios on different industrial sectors
among APEC member economies by using a computable general equilibrium (CGE)
model.
The study drew widespread attention and interest from the audience. Its
conclusion found three things:
First, a state¡¦s increased economic welfare attributed to access to a trade
agreement does not imply that each sector within that state will equally
benefit. Based on the rationale of international division of labor and
comparative advantage, the agreement is likely to give more impetus to
originally competitive sectors, while further limiting vulnerable sectors.
Therefore, policymakers should thoroughly calculate the pros and cons to
maximize the positive effects and minimize the consequences.
Second, the choice of which agreement to join is important. Different trade
routes pose dissimilar challenges. For instance, simulated results suggest that
Japan¡¦s automobile industry may gain more by becoming a TPP member rather than
by joining the RCEP. In other words, if a state carefully calculates before
jumping into an arrangement, it may discover it prefers one route over another
based on its assessments of industrial interests.
If the decisionmakers do not make a thorough assessment, they may mistakenly
allow their vulnerable sectors to encounter intense competition too early.
However, if the state chooses wisely, it can effectively leverage its
competitive industries to expand their market shares. So selection and timing
are crucial strategic decisions that must be made.
Third, because there are both positive and negative repercussions, it is vital
for each state to consider carefully whether its winners from the deal are
suited to a national strategy for economic development, and whether it is
willing to bear the political and economic consequences of the adverse effects.
Free trade does not provide a guarantee of economic growth and prosperity,
neither does it prescribe a magical dose of industrial competitiveness. Without
cautious assessments, the negative impacts could turn a state¡¦s sanguine
expectations into a long-lasting nightmare.
The ongoing controversies and opposition to the cross-strait service trade
agreement demonstrate the importance of prudent decisionmaking, especially when
the outcomes are expected to have long-term repercussions on domestic interests
and create winners and losers among the nation¡¦s industries.
Eric Chiou is a deputy head for FTA and Regional Integration at the Economic
Development Strategy Planning Center, Taiwan Institute of Economic Research.
|